Each component of aggregate
demand can be affected by governmental policies. If potential output in the
short term is fixed, government policies that affect aggregate demand can
affect the unemployment rate and the inflation rate. However, many of the
policy tools available to the government act with a time lag, and as a result
is it quite difficult to keep aggregate demand constantly at the desired level.
The desired level (potential output) is itself constantly changing (usually
increasing). Households and firms have minds of their own, and may not behave
as predicted—the household savings rate and firms’ investment rates can vary
widely. Finally, there are likely to be exogenous shocks to the economy, like
natural disasters, sudden changes in import prices, currency crises, etc.
There are two main categories
of government economic policy. Fiscal policy involves control of government
expenditure and taxation. Monetary policy involves control over the supply of
money and hence interest rates.
If the level of demand in an
economy equals potential output (Q), then no “gap” exists. However, most of the
time the two will not be equal. When aggregate demand is lower than potential
output, unemployment over and above the “full employment rate of unemployment”
will exist and resources will be wasted.
When aggregate demand is
greater than potential output, it is impossible to increase production and
therefore prices will rise, resulting in an “inflationary gap.” Eventually, as
prices rise, marginal buyers will drop out and demand will decrease to a new
full employment equilibrium at a higher price level.
In order to avoid either
inflation or unemployment, the government must attempt to equate aggregate
demand with potential output, ie force demand towards the value D2. This is the
only level of demand at which Q=Y. This simple model shows no inflationary
pressure at full employment. Suppose the government is successful in one year
in equating Q=Y. However, investment has taken place, so next year potential
output will be Q2 > Q. If aggregate demand remains at Y, an
output/employment gap will exist. In order to maintain full employment the
government will need to estimate Q2 and move to a new level of
aggregate demand Y2 such that Y2=Q2. The
government must continue to estimate potential output and, through fiscal and
monetary policy, control aggregate demand in subsequent periods so that Y3=Q3,
Y4=Q4, etc. Needless to say, this is quite a difficult
problem.
Under normal economic
conditions where Q is increasing from year to year, the government will have to
increase Y to match. There are three ways of increasing Y:
·
Government
expenditure
·
Reduction in
taxation
·
Increase in money
supply
If the government increases
expenditure, Y is immediately increased by the amount of the expenditure
because government demand is part of aggregate demand. However, for the firms
producing the goods and services and the households who own resources used by
the firms, income will increase. Some of this new income will be spent on
additional goods and services. There is therefore a multiplier effect where DY = kDG. In order to
increase aggregate demand from Y1 to Y2, the government
can simply increase its expenditures by (Y2-Y1)/k.
Similarly, cutting taxes will
increase Y by some multiple of the amount of the tax cut. The fact of the tax
cut does not in itself constitute an increase in demand, because the money is
not spent on goods as it is in the case of a government expenditure increase.
However, the multiplier effect still comes into play as households and firms
spend some portion of the increased income provided by the lower tax rate.
Lowering taxes and increasing
expenditures are both examples of fiscal policy. The monetary policy solution
to low aggregate demand is to increase the money supply faster than the growth
in the demand for money. This will cause the price of money—the interest rate,
R—to fall. Borrowers (both households and firms) take the cost of borrowing
into account when considering taking out a loan. Thus a decrease in R normally
results in an increase in borrowing and a resulting increase in Y as the
borrowed money is spent on goods and services. Again, the initial round of
expenditure will trigger a multiplier effect as the increased income to firms
and households results in additional rounds of expenditure and new income.
The process of controlling
demand through money supply is complex. The policymaker must first estimate
both current Q and Y and the expected change in Q for which Y should be
adjusted. This will give the change in Y to be desired. Then, the size of the
multiplier must be estimated, which will give the amount of the initial
increase in expenditure that will result in the desired overall increase in Y.
Then, the sensitivity of consumers and businesses to interest rate changes must
be estimated, to determine the change in R that will result in the desired new
expenditures. Finally, the current rate of increase of demand for money must be
estimated, which will lead to an estimate of the rate of increase of money
supply that will result in the desired interest rate. If any significant
changes occur while the process is under way, the estimates may be wrong and
the process may have to be re-started.
Of course, a combination of
fiscal and monetary policy can be used. Tax cuts and increased government
expenditure cannot be maintained forever; eventually problems with high
government debt will surface. Monetary policy depends on consumers’ and
business managers’ expectations and attitudes, which change frequently. And
while the goal of closing the inflationary or employment gaps is universally
desirable, other social values outside the realm of economics will also
contribute to decisions on government policy. Macroeconomic goals generally
accepted as desirable are:
·
Low inflation
rate
·
Low unemployment
rate
·
Balanced
government budget
·
Trade balance
·
Stable currency
in international exchange markets
There is less agreement about
the ideal distribution of Y across C, I and G. Liberals prefer more G than
convervatives. Rates of investment vary widely across different nations. There
is no widely accepted notion of the ideal tax structure. And our simple model
is capable of achieving full employment without inflation, which may not be
true of real-world economies which have an inflationary bias. Finally, other
social values outside the economic spectrum—like the idea that everyone should
be able to get a job—constrain the range of actions available to enact
desirable economic policy.
0 Comments:
Post a Comment